2. The politics of "meaningful
participation": how meaningful is meaningful? A. Will the US ratify the protocol? India and
China hold the key The US position has been carefully orchestrated to be dependent on the action of developing countries This position became the pillar of US negotiations and remains so. President Clinton clearly stated that his country will not agree to "binding obligations unless key developing countries meaningfully participated in this effort." In July 1997, the US senate passed a 95-0 non-binding Byrd-Hagel resolution which called on the president "not to sign any treaty or agreement in Kyoto unless two basic conditions were met. First, the resolution directed the president not to sign any treaty that placed legally binding obligations on the United States to limit or reduce greenhouse gas emissions unless the protocol or agreement also mandates new specific scheduled commitments to limit or reduce greenhouse gas emissions for developing country parties within the same compliance period. The second requirement of the resolution was that the president should not sign any treaty that would result in serious harm to the economy of the US." This resolution continues to shape the US position. Responding to criticism by John Passacantando, director of an NGO called Ozone Action, Senators Robert Byrd, a Democrat and Chuck Hagel, a Republican, defended the role of the Senate in determining the US policy on climate change. "Our legislative branch is not meant to be a rubber stamp for our executive branch. The administration can negotiate but only the Senate can provide the consent necessary to give any treaty the force of law in the US." They insisted also that "the agreement reached in Kyoto does not meet either of the criteria laid out in the Byrd-Hagel resolution." And until the tests were met, the protocol should not be signed by the President3. What is now also evident is that the US negotiating position is crafted on this basis. Its first step was to ask for something vague and undefined as "meaningful participation from developing countries" so that the ball would move to developing countries to say what they could do and of course, the US could easily dismiss it as "not meaningful enough". If the US had proposed, most likely, everyone would have opposed. Therefore, it was best to leave it undefined, but threatening. The US strategy also included making it clear that it would walk out of the Kyoto protocol unless developing countries proposed actions that the US considered "meaningful". Its second step was to get as good or weak an agreement as possible in Kyoto, make it clear it was a partial solution and not try for ratification immediately. And its third step was, or is, to use the threat of non-ratification and opposition from the Senate unless there is "meaningful participation" from the developing countries. On December 8, 1997 Vice President Al Gore told a press conference in Kyoto that "in order to sign an agreement, or in order to send an agreement to the Senate, we must have meaningful participation by key developing countries." Gore stressed again at the end of Kyoto, "lets be clear, we will not submit this agreement for ratification until key developing nations participate in this effort."4 The pressure on the developing countries will therefore mount as the worlds media targets their attention on their non-participation, which will be seen as holding up ratification by the US. Everyone knows that without the US, the Kyoto protocol is meaningless. And every effort will be made to bind the "reluctant" developing countries in the interest of "us all". B. Clean Development Mechanism: inequity in
dealings The Clean Development Mechanism is as unclear as it possibly is unclean. Southern governments that had staunchly opposed the Joint Implementation project based investment to get carbon credits accepted it simply because of a change of the name, from the hated Joint Implementation to a softer (more money-sounding) Clean Development Mechanism. It will be recalled that in its first incarnation, the Global Environment Facility was called the Clean Development Fund and it is quite possible that negotiators in Kyoto halls had wool pulled over their sleepy eyes. It is interesting that the CDM was proposed by Brazil, but as part of a comprehensive burden sharing strategy. But the present CDM, taken completely out of context, is only Joint Implementation and should be renamed as such. The Clean Development Mechanism is as unclear as it is unclean Take away the confusing words surrounding each sentence and what is left of this article 12 of the Kyoto Protocol:
The South must call a spade a spade and must develop its own positions in full knowledge of its own costs and benefits. The scramble for a piece of the brokerage a percentage of the transactions costs has already begun and meetings are being held to convince the South to succumb to this temptation. The US proposes to pay as little as US $14-23 per tonne for its emission credits. Their cost for domestic emission reduction would have been US $125 per tonne Speaking at a recent meeting organised by the Delhi based Tata Energy Research Institute interestingly sponsored by the JUSSCANNZ group of countries (Australia, Japan, Norway and United States) who have launched the Kyoto initiative to get developing countries to agree to commitments, John Palmisano, director, Environmental Policy and Compliance of Enron International said," CDM is the son of JI. For anyone shopping for cheap emission reduction options, the first option would be CDM project investment in the South then JI project investment in Eastern Europe and Russia, and last would be to look at action to be undertaken domestically." The key issue is price. What price would the South be paid for its emission units? The interest of the North is to buy these emissions as cheaply as possible. The US administrations calculations for its bill to meet the Kyoto commitments is "modest" according to its official position simply because it plans to buy as much as 93 per cent of its emission units at the cheapest cost in the market place. The US proposes to pay as little as US$ 14-23 per tonne for its emissions credits. The price the country would have to make for domestic emission reduction programme would be US$ 125 per tonne. The interest is to bargain for the "cheapest and most efficient deal". One approach to get the best deal is to develop a portfolio approach which drives each project to compete against each other. Effectively leaving the buyer to pick and choose and arm twist for the best option. The World Banks Prototype Carbon Fund is one effort in this direction (see box). The Bank has received funding from a number of utility companies and Scandinavian governments to start developing a portfolio of projects from the South. The Bank expects to play the role of an "honest broker" in this trade. The Bank expects to get clearance from its own Executive Board for this proposal in early June and then plans a meeting with its investors in Helsinki to finalise the Fund.
Interestingly, the Banks proposal has reportedly run into hot water with the US administration. The treasury which coordinates the Banks activities has allegedly put on record that it is against any effort to increase the price of carbon units. Under the Banks proposal the industrialised countries would have to pay a nominally higher rate per tonne of carbon. This approach of the cost-plus is not favoured by the administration which would like the market- minus approach. And this when the price that is being discussed is only US$ 20-30 per tonne in the early years, stabilising to US$ 10 per tonne of carbon units bought. It is vital for the South to understand the implications of this cost issue. It has to realise that the cheap option that it is offering the North today will be at a heavy cost to it in the future. Developing countries will use up their cheap options for reducing emissions and not even get credits for it in the global balance sheet. And when the South has reached high levels of energy efficiency and the cost of curtailing emissions will be high domestically, the North will have no economic incentive to invest in these countries. And if global warming is still a threat as it is most likely to be with the industrialised countries not taking any action domestically then the pressure will mount on developing countries to take the tough expensive route. The market is so distorted simply because it has no rights of property of the sellers in this case. It is vital that a clear system of entitlements is set up so that the market can function with the property rights clearly defined and enunciated. |
||